Misbehaving Book Summary
The Making of Behavioral Economics
Book by Richard Thaler
Summary
Richard Thaler chronicles the emergence of behavioral economics, challenging traditional economic assumptions about economics, and revolutionizing our understanding of decision-making. Thaler demonstrates the power of behavioral insights to improve people's lives while shedding light on the profoundly human factors that shape our choices.
Sign in to rate
Average Rating: 1
1. Beginnings: 1970-1978
Economists Assume Irrelevant Factors Don't Matter, But They Do
Standard economic theory assumes that people make rational decisions based only on relevant factors. However, behavioral economics recognizes that in the real world, many supposedly irrelevant factors (SIFs) heavily influence behavior. Examples include:
- Framing effects (e.g. 70/100 feels much worse than 96/137 even if the percentage is the same)
- Anchoring (being influenced by arbitrary reference points)
- Availability bias (judging frequency by how easily examples come to mind) SIFs make behavior deviate from what rational models predict. Identifying SIFs and how they impact decisions is a key aim of behavioral economics.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
The Endowment Effect
The endowment effect refers to the finding that people tend to value items they own more highly than identical items they do not own, even if they acquired the item recently or by chance. Examples include:
- Participants given a mug demanded significantly more money to part with it than others were willing to pay to acquire the same mug
- People refuse to sell bottles of wine for prices they would never pay to acquire those bottles
- List prices create an "anchor" that sellers then demand more than, but buyers are unwilling to pay
The endowment effect shows that ownership itself (even very recent ownership) makes people value items more. This violates standard economic assumptions of fungibility and stable preferences. Loss aversion likely underpins the effect - giving something up feels like a loss.
Section: 1, Chapter: 2
Mere Ownership Makes Us Overvalue Items
Be aware that your tendency to overvalue what you already own can lead to poor decisions, such as:
- Holding on to losing investments rather than cutting your losses
- Refusing to part with items you no longer need
- Overpricing items you're trying to sell
- Turning down good deals because you're anchored to a higher price you previously paid
Section: 1, Chapter: 2
Anomalies In Behavior
Early in his career, Richard Thaler started collecting examples of anomalies - human behaviors that deviated from the predictions of standard economic models. Some examples from his list:
- Paying more attention to sunk costs than rational models say we should
- Refusing to buy or sell items based on apparently irrelevant factors like recent ownership
- Failing to ignore past costs when making decisions
- Avoiding options to constrain our future behavior
At the time, these anomalies were seen as quirks or mistakes, not fundamentally important. But Thaler saw them as clues that the rational models were flawed and needed to be revised to incorporate human psychology.
Section: 1, Chapter: 3
Prospect Theory
Prospect theory, developed by Kahneman and Tversky, provided a formal alternative to the standard economic theory of expected utility. A key element is the value function, which has several important features:
These features explained many of the anomalies Thaler had identified, like the endowment effect. Loss aversion makes people reluctant to part with items they already own. The value function's shape also implies risk aversion for gains but risk seeking for losses.
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
Focus On Changes Rather Than Absolute Levels
We experience life as changes, not absolute levels. As such, we should:
- Evaluate outcomes as gains or losses relative to a reference point. E.g., a 5% raise feels better if others got 3% than if they got 7%.
- Losses hurt about twice as much as equivalent gains feel good. Be more cautious about risks that could lead to loss.
- Because of diminishing sensitivity, look for opportunities to break up gains (to make each one feel bigger) and combine losses (to make them feel less bad overall).
- Since losses are so painful, think carefully before giving something up, even if you'll get something else of equal value in return. Is it worth the pain of the loss?
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
Behavioral Economics Had A Slow Start
In the late 1970s, Richard Thaler was a young professor trying to apply psychology to economics, but with a hard time getting others to take his ideas seriously. A few key moments:
- On a drive to Stanford, he pondered how to convince skeptical economists that psychological factors really do affect economic decisions
- He discovered the work of Kahneman and Tversky on heuristics, biases and prospect theory, which provided an academic foundation for his ideas
- At Stanford, he met Baruch Fischhoff, Paul Slovic and others studying human judgment, further expanding his knowledge of relevant psychology
However, the economic establishment still viewed behavioral approaches as quirky at best and misguided at worst.
Section: 1, Chapter: 5
The Endowment Effect Proved Challenging To Demonstrate
One of the key early findings in behavioral economics was the endowment effect - our tendency to value things we own more highly than identical things we don't own. However, Thaler and colleagues ran into several challenges in trying to demonstrate the effect:
- Experimental subjects had to be making real choices with real money at stake, not just hypothetical survey responses, or else economists would dismiss the results
- The experiments had to rule out alternative explanations like transaction costs or implied information value
- Results had to be replicated across different item types and with high levels of statistical significance
In the end, carefully designed experiments involving things like trading mugs and pens provided convincing evidence. But the process illustrates the high burden of proof required to shift established economic wisdom, even in the face of compelling anomalies.
Section: 1, Chapter: 6
Economists' Objections Presented A "Gauntlet"
As Thaler and colleagues tried to publish early behavioral economics research, they encountered a predictable set of objections from economists, which Thaler dubbed the "Gauntlet":
1
The stakes weren't high enough - people will behave rationally when big money is on the line2
People will learn their way out of biases over time3
In markets, individual biases will cancel out4
Arbitrage by rational actors will eliminate any impact of bias on pricesOvercoming these objections required careful experimental designs and an accumulation of empirical evidence across many studies. But the gauntlet also revealed the reluctance of many economists to incorporate psychological realism into their models, even in the face of contrary evidence.
Section: 1, Chapter: 6
2. Mental Accounting: 1979-85
Perceived Fairness Affects Willingness To Pay
The "beer on the beach" study illustrates how perceived fairness affects willingness to pay, even for identical products. Thaler asked people to imagine buying a beer from either a fancy resort hotel or a run-down grocery store. The catch: the beer is to be consumed on the beach, so the drinking experience will be identical.
Results showed people were willing to pay much more for the beer from the resort ($7.25 on average) than for the one from the store ($4.10). The location's perceived fairness as a reference point shaped their valuations, even though the consumption experience was the same. This effect, which Thaler calls "transaction utility," has important implications for pricing decisions.
Section: 2, Chapter: 7
Maximize Perceived Transaction Utility In Your Pricing
To make your prices feel fair and maximize consumers' willingness to pay:
- Position your offering as being "on sale" or "a bargain" compared to reference prices (e.g., "lista price," competitors)
- Articulate reasons why your price is fair given your costs, product quality, target market, etc.
- Avoid blatant cash grabs or price hikes that will feel like "rip-offs" (e.g., surge pricing during emergencies)
- Consider obscuring or shrouding certain costs to minimize "pain of paying" (e.g., shipping & handling)
- Make price increases feel fair by offering some additional value at the same time
Remember: perceived fairness is often more important than actual price level in driving purchase behavior. A bargain-hunting mentality keeps retailers like Costco in business. Focus first on perception, not just on the nominal price.
Section: 2, Chapter: 7
Sunk Costs Leads Us To Throw Good Money After Bad
The sunk cost fallacy is our tendency to continue an endeavor once we've invested time, effort or money into it, even when continuing is no longer rational. An example from Thaler's personal life illustrates how mental accounting can exacerbate the effect.
Actively spending money makes the sunk cost highly vivid and painful if the purchase isn't then utilized. We feel the need to "get our money's worth." But this means we often throw good money (or time or effort) after bad, continuing down an unprofitable path.
Section: 1, Chapter: 8
Mental Accounting
People often use mental budgets or "buckets" to constrain their spending - e.g., $200/month on dining out. But this heuristic can lead to irrational behavior.
In one study, subjects were told they were going to a play. Half were told they had recently spent $50 going to a basketball game (same bucket), while half were told they got a $50 parking ticket (different bucket). Subjects were then asked if they would still buy a ticket to the play.
Those who had gone to the game were less likely to buy play tickets, presumably because they felt they had already spent their entertainment budget for the month. But this makes no sense - the historical spending is a sunk cost and should be irrelevant to the play decision. Yet because it was categorized in the same mental bucket, it still affected their choice.
Section: 2, Chapter: 9
Gambling With The House's Money
When gamblers are ahead in a gambling session, they often take bigger risks than they would otherwise. It's as if they consider the winnings to be "the house's money," not their own, so they're more willing to risk it.
Conversely, when gamblers are in the hole, they tend to chase their losses with bigger bets, hoping to break even again. They become risk-seeking rather than risk-averse in the domain of losses.
Thaler observed both of these tendencies in his own regular poker games with friends. When players were ahead for the session, they played looser and more aggressively. When they were behind, they would often take big risks in hopes of getting back to even. The math of poker suggests neither approach is ideal - your overall wealth should determine your risk tolerance, not your results in one session. But these deep psychological tendencies are hard to overcome.
Section: 2, Chapter: 10
3. Self-Control: 1975-88
Willpower? No Problem
While modern economic theory assumes that people have perfect self-control, early economists like Adam Smith and Irving Fisher recognized the importance of willpower and the fact that people often struggle to resist short-term temptations.
Smith wrote extensively about "passion" and the need to overcome it through reason. Fisher described impatient behavior by low-income people, such as workers getting drunk after payday rather than saving.
It wasn't until the 1930s-50s that economists like Paul Samuelson, seeking to make economics more mathematically rigorous, introduced the idea that people discount the future at a constant rate and have perfect self-control. This assumption became standard in economic models, even though it contradicted many earlier thinkers' insights about the very real problem of limited willpower.
Section: 3, Chapter: 11
We Overvalue Immediate Rewards
Economists model intertemporal choice (i.e., decisions involving tradeoffs between the present and future) using the discounted utility model developed by Paul Samuelson. A key assumption is that people discount the future at a constant rate.
But behavioral research shows that real people tend to discount the future at a much higher rate in the short run than in the long run. Given a choice between $100 today and $120 a month from now, many people choose the immediate $100. But given a choice between $100 a year from now and $120 a year and a month from now, most people choose the $120. The difference in timing is the same (one month), but when that difference is in the future rather than the present, people are more patient.
This tendency is known as hyperbolic discounting. Like looking through a telescope, differences in the near future appear much larger than equivalent differences in the distant future. This inconsistency can lead to problems of self-control and procrastination.
Section: 3, Chapter: 11
The Planner and the Doer
Thaler proposes a "planner-doer" model to understand self-control problems:
- The "planner" is the far-sighted self that makes plans for the future and wants to make good long-term decisions
- The "doer" is the short-sighted self that acts in the moment and is susceptible to temptation
The planner has to anticipate the doer's weaknesses and set up commitments, rules, penalties or incentives to keep the doer on track. But the doer looks for loopholes in the heat of the moment. We are, in effect, in constant negotiation with ourselves.
Section: 3, Chapter: 12
Commit In Advance
Since our short-term impulses often undermine our long-term interests, one of the most effective self-control strategies is precommitment - locking in a good decision before temptation arises. Some examples:
- Buying junk food in small packages rather than bulk to avoid overeating
- Using apps to restrict social media use during work hours
- Signing up for workout classes with a cancellation fee
- Investing in a 401(k) that penalizes early withdrawals
- Keeping your credit card at home when going out to avoid overspending
The key is to anticipate the temptations your "doer" will face in the future and take steps now to limit the damage.
Section: 3, Chapter: 12
4. Working With Danny: 1984-85
Fairness Games
The Ultimatum Game is a famous experiment in behavioral economics that tests people's perceptions of fairness.
Player A is given a sum of money (the "pie") and told they must offer some share of it to Player B
- If Player B accepts the offer, both players get the agreed amounts
- If Player B rejects, neither player gets anything
Even though Player B should rationally accept any positive offer, since something is better than nothing, in practice offers perceived as unfairly low (usually below 20% of the total) are often rejected.
With skin in the game, people are even more willing to sacrifice to enforce fairness. The Ultimatum Game reveals a deep human aversion to getting shortchanged.
Section: 4, Chapter: 15
Exchange Asymmetries Lead To Fewer Trades
The "mug experiments" were a series of studies designed to test the endowment effect - people's tendency to value items they own more highly than equivalent items they do not own.
In the experiments, some participants were given coffee mugs and became potential sellers, while others became potential buyers. According to standard economic theory, about 50% of the mugs should trade hands, since the mugs were allocated randomly.
However, in repeated experiments, only 10-30% of the mugs traded. Sellers' minimum acceptable price was typically about twice as high as buyers' maximum willingness to pay.
This effect persists even if participants are allowed to handle the mugs in advance or learn the market price. It appears to reflect a deep aversion to losing items we own, rather than just a lack of information. And it directly contradicts the Coase theorem, a classic economic principle which holds that in the absence of transaction costs, goods will always flow to their most valued use.
Section: 4, Chapter: 16
5. Engaging With The Economics Profession: 1986-94
The Debate Begins
In 1985, the University of Chicago held a conference on behavioral economics, pitting leading behavioral researchers like Kahneman, Tversky and Thaler against prominent skeptics from the Chicago school of economics.
Kahneman and Tversky presented their famous "Asian disease problem," showing how framing influences risk preferences. They also shared findings on fairness and loss aversion, the endowment effect and mental accounting.
Economists largely dismissed the behavioral evidence as a collection of "quirks" that would be eliminated by market forces. They argued that psychological factors were irrelevant as long as the aggregate predictions of rational models were correct.
The heated debate crystallized the core points of contention between the behavioral and neoclassical camps. While minds were not changed overnight, the conference put behavioral economics on the map as an important emerging field.
Section: 5, Chapter: 17
Narrow Framing on Upper East Side
Narrow framing is the tendency to evaluate risks in isolation rather than as part of an overall portfolio. This can lead to suboptimal decisions.
- Investors hold low-return bonds in taxable accounts while holding stocks in tax-free retirement accounts (the opposite of what tax efficiency dictates)
- Employees buy company stock in their 401(k), duplicating (rather than diversifying) risks from their human capital
- Casino gamblers bet more recklessly with winnings ("house money") than with money from their own pockets
Experiments on risky choice find that people make different decisions when choices are presented one at a time (narrow framing) vs. collectively. People will reject a single risky bet but accept a package of similar bets, even though the aggregate risks and returns may be equivalent.
Narrow framing can lead people to be risk averse in some contexts and risk seeking in others, deviating from global risk neutrality. It's a pervasive bias that influences many real-world choices, from casino floors to corporate boardrooms.
Section: 5, Chapter: 20
Think Broadly To Optimize Risk-Taking
To optimize your risk taking:
Section: 5, Chapter: 20
6. Finance: 1983-2003
The Stock Market Is Like Keynes's Beauty Contest
John Maynard Keynes likened the stock market to a newspaper beauty contest in which readers try to pick the most popular faces among other readers, leading to an infinite regress of anticipating what others believe average opinion will be.
Similarly, investors don't just evaluate stocks based on fundamentals. They also try to anticipate other investors' valuations, which leads to self-reinforcing bubbles and crashes. The result is a market driven by "animal spirits" and herd behavior rather than rational analysis.
As Keynes wrote: "The actual, private object of the most skilled investment today is...to outwit the crowd, and to pass the bad, or depreciating, half-crown to the other fellow...this battle of wits to anticipate the basis of conventional valuation a few months hence, rather than the prospective yield of an investment over a long term of years, does not even require gulls amongst the public to feed the maws of the professional; - it can be played by professionals amongst themselves."
The implication is that stock prices can diverge significantly from fundamental values, and that making money in markets requires anticipating these swings in sentiment. This view contradicts the efficient market hypothesis but accords with behavioral finance and the reality of market booms and busts.
Section: 5, Chapter: 21
Does the Stock Market Overreact?
If markets are efficient, stock prices should respond quickly and accurately to new information. But empirical studies find pervasive evidence of both underreaction and overreaction.
Examples of underreaction:
- Post-earnings announcement drift: stocks with surprisingly good (bad) earnings outperform (underperform) for months after the announcement
- Momentum: stocks with strong (weak) returns over the past 3-12 months tend to continue outperforming (underperforming) in the next 3-12 months
Examples of overreaction:
- Long-term reversals: stocks with strong (weak) returns over the past 3-5 years tend to underperform (outperform) over the next 3-5 years
- Value/growth: "value" stocks with low price/earnings ratios outperform "growth" stocks with high P/E ratios, contrary to efficient markets logic
Section: 5, Chapter: 22
Value Investing Challenges The Efficient Market Hypothesis
The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) holds that stock prices instantly and accurately reflect all available information. This implies it's impossible to consistently "beat the market" by buying undervalued stocks or selling overvalued ones.
However, value investing strategies, which involve buying stocks with low price-to-earnings or price-to-book ratios, have historically outperformed growth strategies. Fama and French (1992) confirmed the outperformance of value stocks, contradicting the EMH.
Behavioral economists argue this reflects mispricing due to investor overreaction. When a stock disappoints, investors overreact and push its price below fundamental value, creating a value opportunity. When it exceeds expectations, overreaction makes it overpriced.
But EMH defenders argue value stocks are simply riskier, so their higher returns just compensate for this. The question remains unresolved, illustrating the challenges in distinguishing mispricing from risk premiums.
Section: 5, Chapter: 23
The Price is Not Right
According to the efficient market hypothesis, stock prices should reflect the discounted value of a firm's future cash flows. This implies prices should only change when new information about cash flows arrives.
But Robert Shiller (1981) found that stock prices are much more volatile than the dividend streams they supposedly reflect. A firm's stock price can double or halve even when its underlying dividends and earnings are stable.
This "excess volatility" puzzle challenges market efficiency. If prices only reflect fundamentals, why do they swing so wildly in the absence of concrete news?
Shiller argued this reflects "fads, fashions, and bubbles" among investors. Prices are driven by sentiment and speculation as much as real information. This explains why prices move more than fundamentals.
Section: 5, Chapter: 24
Don't Get Anchored On Arbitrary Prices
The tendency of closed-end fund prices to diverge from net asset values illustrates a general behavioral pitfall - anchoring on arbitrary reference points. For example:
- Fixating on a "target price" for a stock rather than adjusting to new information
- Basing purchase decisions on the 52-week high or low price
- Treating an IPO price as informative of a stock's "true value"
To avoid this trap:
- Base fair value estimates on fundamentals (cash flows, assets, growth) rather than historical prices
- Be willing to walk away from investments when the price deviates from your valuation model
- Avoid fixating on realized gains/losses; consider only future expected returns
- Update target prices as new information arrives; don't get anchored on old ones
- Remember the market price is just one opinion of value; develop your own independent view
Behavioral finance teaches that prices can diverge from fundamentals due to investor irrationality. Savvy investors think for themselves rather than just trusting the market. Independent analysis is the best anchor.
Section: 5, Chapter: 25
7. Welcome To Chicago: 1995-Present
Introducing Behavioral Economics To The Legal Academy
Thaler and colleagues sought to bring insights from behavioral economics to the analysis of legal rules and regulations.
This behavioral law and economics approach contrasts with traditional law and economics, which relies heavily on rational choice theory. For instance, behavioral research shows the Coase theorem may fail due to endowment effects and fairness concerns, even with low transaction costs.
Likewise, behavioral findings on limited self-control, overconfidence, and impatience suggest regulations like mandatory retirement savings or consumer protection may sometimes be justified, challenging libertarian anti-paternalism dogma.
Behavioral law and economics aims to make legal analysis more realistic and empirically-grounded. But it remains controversial, especially the paternalism debate. Nonetheless, it has grown rapidly and influenced numerous legal domains, from contracts to criminal justice to corporate governance.
Section: 6, Chapter: 27
Choice Architectures
Choice architecture - the design of the environment in which people make decisions - can have a big impact on outcomes. Some tips for would-be choice architects:
- Defaults matter - people tend to stick with them due to status quo bias. Make sure they're well-chosen.
- Anchor options matter - an option that's intended to be a decoy or reference point can become a target. Be mindful of what you're anchoring.
- Vivid attributes get overweighted - people fixate on things like square footage because they're easy to compare. Highlight important but less vivid attributes too.
- Emotions drive decisions - envy, ego, identity, FOMO. Anticipate and plan for them, don't just expect rationality.
- Details matter - tiny frictions, visual cues, and choice of units can sway decisions a lot. Sweat the small stuff!
A well-designed choice environment makes the "right" choice (what people would pick with full reflection) the easy choice. A badly-designed one can lead people astray. With some thought, you can nudge people to make better decisions without restricting their freedom.
Section: 6, Chapter: 28
Supposedly Irrelevant Factors Matter
The University of Chicago Booth School of Business moved to a new building and had to decide how to allocate offices. They used a draft system where faculty chose in sequence, with the order determined by a combination of seniority, rank, and merit.
This is a high-stakes decision. Faculty spend hours in their offices and location matters a lot for convenience and status. Surely, the efficient market hypothesis suggests the draft will yield the optimal allocation based on faculty's true preferences, right?
Not quite. In reality, faculty got caught up in minute details like tiny differences in square footage, whether an office had a thermostat, and whether it was on the 5th vs 4th floor (even with no view difference).
Section: 6, Chapter: 28
Process Over Outcomes: Judge Decisions By What's Rational Ex-Ante
It's easy to criticize a decision that worked out badly ex-post. But this can be misleading. Maybe it was a good decision that just had an unlucky outcome. You wouldn't fault a poker player who made a smart strategic bet that happened to lose.
Instead, evaluate decisions based on the quality of the process and the information available ex-ante: A good process will have more good outcomes than bad ones over time. But there will always be some random variation in the short term. Don't let it distract you.
Reward good decisions, even if they sometimes have bad outcomes due to chance. Otherwise, you'll fall prey to outcome bias and end up encouraging reckless risks that just happen to pay off. In the long run, process dominates outcome.
Section: 6, Chapter: 29
8. Helping Out: 2004-Present
Automatic Escalation Helps People Save More
One of the most successful applications of behavioral economics is the "Save More Tomorrow" (SMarT) program to increase retirement savings. Key elements:
- Automatic enrollment - eligible employees are enrolled by default unless they opt out. This harnesses inertia to increase sign-ups.
- Automatic escalation - the savings rate increases automatically over time, typically linked to pay raises. This makes the increase feel less painful.
- Automatic investment - contributions are invested into a default fund allocation unless the employee chooses otherwise. Simplifies a complex choice.
In firms that implemented SMarT, the average savings rate rose from 3.5% to 13.6% over 3-4 years. 78% of those offered the plan joined, far more than with traditional opt-in plans.
SMarT works because it corrects several behavioral biases:
Section: 7, Chapter: 31
Nudging in the UK
The Behavioural Insights Team (BIT), a.k.a. the "Nudge Unit", was set up in the UK Cabinet Office to apply behavioral science to improve public policy. A key innovation was the use of randomized controlled trials (RCTs) to rigorously test behavioral interventions.
For example, to increase tax collection, BIT ran an RCT sending different reminder letters to taxpayers. The most effective letter used social norms, telling recipients that most people in their town paid taxes on time and they were in the minority that hadn't.
This letter increased payment rates by over 5 percentage points, accelerating £9 million in revenue. The trial cost almost nothing since the letters were being sent anyway. Similar RCTs tested interventions in:
- Encouraging people to join the organ donor registry
- Getting people to pay court fines on time
- Motivating job seekers to attend employment training
The UK's example is spreading, with "nudge units" being set up in governments around the world. RCTs are a crucial tool for evidence-based policy, and behavioral science expands the toolkit of solutions.
Section: 6, Chapter: 33
Related Content
Thinking Fast and Slow Book Summary
Daniel Kahneman
Kahneman explores the two systems that drive the way we think: the intuitive, automatic System 1 and the deliberate, analytical System 2. It explores how these systems shape our judgments, decisions, and biases, revealing the surprising power of intuition and the pitfalls of overconfidence.
Kahneman explores the two systems that drive the way we think: the intuitive, automatic System 1 and the deliberate, analytical System 2. It explores how these systems shape our judgments, decisions, and biases, revealing the surprising power of intuition and the pitfalls of overconfidence.
Psychology
Personal Development
Business
The Psychology of Money Book Summary
Morgan Housel
The Psychology of Money is a fascinating look at the strange ways people think about money and teaches you how to make better sense of one of life's most important topics. Doing well with money isn't necessarily about what you know; it's about how you behave, and behavior is hard to teach, even to really smart people.
The Psychology of Money is a fascinating look at the strange ways people think about money and teaches you how to make better sense of one of life's most important topics. Doing well with money isn't necessarily about what you know; it's about how you behave, and behavior is hard to teach, even to really smart people.
Psychology
Money
Self-Help