To maximize profits, lenders and investment banks exploited flaws in the rating agency models:
- Using "thin-file" FICO scores from borrowers with limited credit history
- Focusing on floating-rate loans the agencies favored vs fixed-rate
- Offsetting high-risk loans with safer ones to game the averages
This allowed them to get high ratings on subprime mortgage bonds and CDOs that were far riskier than they appeared. Wall Street insiders knew the game, but the rating agencies were oblivious.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
Every step in the subprime mortgage machine was plagued by misaligned incentives:
- Brokers were paid for volume, not loan quality
- Banks made money from securitizing loans, not holding them
- Rating agencies were paid by banks, not investors
- Investors craved yield, didn't look under the hood
When each player is compensated based on short-term profits rather than long-term sustainability, a system is bound to collapse under its own weight. Understanding incentives is key to spotting financial folly.
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
By mid-2007, the subprime market was starting to crack but most refused to acknowledge it. Insiders like Burry and Lippmann saw clear signs of trouble - soaring default rates, plunging bond prices, massive sell orders from big firms. But in classic "boiling frog" fashion, the system was slow to react. The true believers wrote it off as a blip, clinging to the notion that "housing prices only go up." The naysayers like Burry and Eisman used the calm to double down on their bets, knowing the day of reckoning drew near.
Section: 1, Chapter: 6
From 2005-2007, subprime lending exploded as Wall Street figured out how to game the system. With investors clamoring for higher-yielding bonds, lenders lowered standards, rating agencies blessed risky loans, and investment banks packaged them into complex securities. The fees were so lucrative that everyone from mortgage brokers to CDO managers was incentivized to keep the machine humming, no matter how risky the loans. Few questioned whether it was sustainable - they were too busy getting rich.
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
By early 2007, the subprime mortgage market was starting to crack, but few wanted to acknowledge it. The maverick investors who had bet against it - Burry, Eisman, Ledley & Mai - were seen as Chicken Littles. But they knew they were onto something big. The trick was finding ways to profit from their insight. They embarked on a mad scramble to load up on credit default swaps, short positions, and other contrarian bets before it was too late. It was a treasure hunt where the treasure was hidden in plain sight.
Section: 1, Chapter: 7
In the early 2000s, Steve Eisman, an equity analyst covering consumer finance companies, started noticing troubling trends in the subprime mortgage industry. Lenders like Household Finance were making increasingly risky loans to lower-income borrowers. With the help of his analyst Vinny Daniel, Eisman dug into the details and realized the entire industry was a house of cards built on unsustainable lending practices. They started shorting the stocks of subprime lenders.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
The key to the CDO alchemy that turned risky loans into "safe" securities:
- Pool together a bunch of subprime loans in a CDO
- Slice the CDO into different "tranches" by seniority
- Get rating agencies to bless 80% of the CDO as triple-A
- Make the CDO so complex that investors can't assess true risk
- Keep any unsold risky pieces for next CDO deal
The process worked as long as investors didn't look too closely at the sausage-making. But people like Eisman and Burry saw through the charade.
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
Ways to bet against the housing market before the crash:
- Shorting stocks of subprime lenders and homebuilders
- Buying credit default swaps on subprime mortgage bonds
- Buying puts or shorting subprime mortgage bond indices
The key was spotting the bubble early and finding asymmetric ways to bet against it with limited downside risk. This allowed investors like Eisman and Burry to make huge profits when it popped.
Section: 1, Chapter: 3
Some of the distinctive features of China's governance model and economic strategy:
- China's political system utilizes a merit-based civil service. Provincial and local officials are held accountable for meeting economic and social targets.
- Confucian values like social harmony, deference to authority, and the primacy of the collective over the individual continue to shape Chinese politics and society. This contrasts with the individualism prized in the West.
- In the economic realm, China has adopted a hybrid model blending market-based incentives and competition with strong state direction over key industries and the financial system. Capitalism subordinated to Communist Party control.
- China's leadership takes a long-term view of its development, with grand plans like the Belt and Road Initiative aiming to extend its economic reach across Eurasia. It has also focused heavily on boosting its technological capabilities to avoid dependence on the West.
Section: 2, Chapter: 12
Long-term debt cycles, lasting 50-100 years on average, follow a predictable pattern:
- They begin with little debt and "hard money" like gold.
- Credit expands through claims on hard money.
- Debt levels rise as lending and borrowing increase.
- Debt crises emerge as debts exceed the ability to repay. Hard money constraints are abandoned in favor of fiat money.
- Fiat money is printed excessively, leading to the devaluation of money.
- Eventually a return to hard money occurs to restore confidence.
This cycle has repeated throughout history, from Ancient Rome to Medieval China to 20th century Europe and America. While new financial instruments emerge, the underlying dynamics persist because of the universal human tendency towards credit expansions and contractions.
Section: 1, Chapter: 3
Chapter 9 traces the rise of the Dutch Empire in the 17th century:
- The Dutch successfully revolted against Spain in the 80 Years' War, asserting independence in 1581. This allowed them to create a more open, inventive society.
- The Dutch pioneered key innovations like joint-stock companies, stock markets, and central banking that provided fuel for commerce and expansion. The Dutch East India Company became the world's first mega-corporation.
- The Dutch had strong education, a culture emphasizing saving and hard work, and invested in their military to protect trade routes. Amsterdam became the world's financial center and the Dutch guilder emerged as the first reserve currency.
- At their peak around 1650, the Dutch had the highest incomes in Europe and dominated world trade.
Section: 2, Chapter: 9
Looking back over the last few centuries, all major currencies have either been devalued significantly or died altogether. Currencies are devalued when governments print excessive amounts of money, usually to finance budget deficits or service high debt levels. This reduces the purchasing power of money over time. Many currencies have been completely replaced, often after losing a war or during a political revolution. The only major currencies that have survived since 1850 are the U.S. dollar, British pound and Swiss franc - and even they have lost over 90% of their purchasing power due to devaluations.
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
While currency devaluation can seem like a gradual process, history shows it often happens abruptly during times of crisis. When government debts become unsustainable, devaluation is the only politically feasible solution. This happened in Weimar Germany in the 1920s, the U.S. and Europe in the 1930s, and many emerging economies in the late 20th century. Such rapid devaluations can destroy wealth stored in the currency, creating social and political unrest. Investors must be alert to signs of unsustainable debt and political disorder that could trigger a currency crisis.
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
All societies have internal struggles between different socioeconomic classes over wealth and power. These conflicts intensify when there are large gaps in wealth and fundamental values between the classes. Wealth gaps naturally emerge in capitalist systems, as some benefit more from productivity gains than others.
Values gaps emerge as people coalesce into "tribes" based on factors like religion, ethnicity, urban/rural status, and politics. When a country experiences economic hardships on top of these gaps, it often leads to a breaking point of revolution and/or civil war to restructure the internal order. Managing these internal gaps is essential for countries to maintain stability and avoid self-destructive conflicts.
Section: 1, Chapter: 5
For countries and individuals, wealth and power accumulate when production exceeds consumption. Being able to produce more valuable goods and services than you consume is what allows you to save and invest for the future. Likewise, great empires and economies emerge when they are highly productive in creating things the world wants.
The most powerful countries have the economic output and trade surpluses to finance strong militaries and global influence. When countries turn to over-consumption and under-production, running chronic deficits, it inevitably leads to a decline in relative wealth and power. Investors must watch whether countries are living within their means or borrowing excessively from the future.
Section: 1, Chapter: 6
The US has weaponized the dollar's global primacy to restrict China's access to the international financial system. This has incentivized China to develop alternative payment channels and make its own currency more internationally accessible. China holds over $1 trillion in US Treasury debt, which some fear it could dump in a crisis. This would be highly disruptive to global markets.
More broadly, the US-China trade war and moves toward "decoupling" disrupt the intricate supply chains that have fueled global prosperity. Businesses face pressure to relocate out of China. A world split into rival economic blocs would be less efficient and dynamic. A key question is whether China can reduce its dependence on Western technologies in critical areas like semiconductors. The risk is a destabilizing race for technological superiority with military applications.
Section: 2, Chapter: 13
While modern economic theory assumes that people have perfect self-control, early economists like Adam Smith and Irving Fisher recognized the importance of willpower and the fact that people often struggle to resist short-term temptations.
Smith wrote extensively about "passion" and the need to overcome it through reason. Fisher described impatient behavior by low-income people, such as workers getting drunk after payday rather than saving.
It wasn't until the 1930s-50s that economists like Paul Samuelson, seeking to make economics more mathematically rigorous, introduced the idea that people discount the future at a constant rate and have perfect self-control. This assumption became standard in economic models, even though it contradicted many earlier thinkers' insights about the very real problem of limited willpower.
Section: 3, Chapter: 11
The "mug experiments" were a series of studies designed to test the endowment effect - people's tendency to value items they own more highly than equivalent items they do not own.
In the experiments, some participants were given coffee mugs and became potential sellers, while others became potential buyers. According to standard economic theory, about 50% of the mugs should trade hands, since the mugs were allocated randomly.
However, in repeated experiments, only 10-30% of the mugs traded. Sellers' minimum acceptable price was typically about twice as high as buyers' maximum willingness to pay.
This effect persists even if participants are allowed to handle the mugs in advance or learn the market price. It appears to reflect a deep aversion to losing items we own, rather than just a lack of information. And it directly contradicts the Coase theorem, a classic economic principle which holds that in the absence of transaction costs, goods will always flow to their most valued use.
Section: 4, Chapter: 16
Standard economic theory assumes that people make rational decisions based only on relevant factors. However, behavioral economics recognizes that in the real world, many supposedly irrelevant factors (SIFs) heavily influence behavior. Examples include:
- Framing effects (e.g. 70/100 feels much worse than 96/137 even if the percentage is the same)
- Anchoring (being influenced by arbitrary reference points)
- Availability bias (judging frequency by how easily examples come to mind) SIFs make behavior deviate from what rational models predict. Identifying SIFs and how they impact decisions is a key aim of behavioral economics.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
John Maynard Keynes likened the stock market to a newspaper beauty contest in which readers try to pick the most popular faces among other readers, leading to an infinite regress of anticipating what others believe average opinion will be.
Similarly, investors don't just evaluate stocks based on fundamentals. They also try to anticipate other investors' valuations, which leads to self-reinforcing bubbles and crashes. The result is a market driven by "animal spirits" and herd behavior rather than rational analysis.
As Keynes wrote: "The actual, private object of the most skilled investment today is...to outwit the crowd, and to pass the bad, or depreciating, half-crown to the other fellow...this battle of wits to anticipate the basis of conventional valuation a few months hence, rather than the prospective yield of an investment over a long term of years, does not even require gulls amongst the public to feed the maws of the professional; - it can be played by professionals amongst themselves."
The implication is that stock prices can diverge significantly from fundamental values, and that making money in markets requires anticipating these swings in sentiment. This view contradicts the efficient market hypothesis but accords with behavioral finance and the reality of market booms and busts.
Section: 5, Chapter: 21
Levitt and Dubner lay out a simple economic framework for understanding the business of prostitution:
- Supply and Demand: When demand from male customers outstrips supply of female prostitutes, prices are high. This explains why prostitutes could earn the equivalent of over $76,000/year in early 1900s Chicago.
- Substitute Goods: Competition from other women willing to have unpaid sex acts as a substitute good, eating into prostitutes' earning power. As premarital sex became more common, demand for paid sex fell.
- Pimps as Managers: Pimps provide legitimate business services (protection from police/johns, marketing, price discrimination) in exchange for a 25% cut. Prostitutes working with pimps earn more per trick.
- Price Discrimination: Pimps charge different prices to black vs white customers to maximize revenue. This first-degree price discrimination extracts more total surplus.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
In the epilogue, Levitt and Dubner describe a provocative experiment by Yale economist Keith Chen. Chen taught capuchin monkeys to use money, then observed their economic behavior. Remarkably, the capuchins exhibited many of the same biases and irrationalities as humans:
- The monkeys responded to price changes, buying less of a food when its price rose
- They fell for the "sunk cost fallacy," eating more of a food they paid more for
- Like humans, the monkeys were loss-averse, strongly preferring gambles framed as bonuses vs. deductions
Levitt and Dubner argue the capuchin experiments hold a mirror up to human nature. If even monkeys exhibit economic biases, it suggests they may be more deeply hardwired than we'd like to admit. The authors believe acknowledging the limits of human rationality is a first step to devising policies and incentives that account for it. Rather than expecting people to act like Econs, they suggest we design systems that anticipate predictably irrational actors.
Section: 1, Chapter: 6
One of the starkest findings from the prostitution data is how the price of oral sex has fallen dramatically relative to vaginal sex compared to the early 1900s. While oral sex used to command a significant price premium, it now sells for a 20% discount. The authors propose two main hypotheses for why this might be:
- Oral sex carries lower risks of pregnancy and disease transmission for the prostitute, making it less costly to provide
- Social taboos around oral sex have diminished over time, increasing supply
This example illustrates how shifting technological realities (birth control/STD risk) and cultural norms (sexual taboos) can reshape the relative value of goods and services. Business leaders can apply this same framework of analyzing how macro trends will impact their industry. Anticipating such shifts allows companies to adapt their offerings, pricing, and positioning to stay ahead of the curve.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
Based on an analysis of data on captured terrorists and would-be terrorists, Levitt and Dubner identify some common traits. Compared to the average person, terrorists are more likely to:
- Rent rather than own a home (due to not expecting to live long)
- Not have a life insurance policy (since it doesn't pay out for suicides)
- Make purchases in cash rather than credit/checks (to avoid paper trail)
- Have multiple ATM withdrawals of just under $3000 (to evade mandatory reporting limits)
The authors propose that banks and insurance companies could potentially use these insights to identify individuals at high risk of committing terrorist acts based on their financial and personal records. Of course, such profiling raises major privacy concerns and could ensnare some innocent people exhibiting these same behaviors. But in theory, companies and law enforcement could leverage this data to proactively intervene with would-be terrorists.
Section: 1, Chapter: 2
Levitt, an economist and father of four, applies economic principles to parenting. His key insights:
- Children are expensive, so have them only if the benefits outweigh the costs
- Think on the margin - don't fret over any one decision, focus on cumulative impact
- Incentives matter - use carrots and sticks to encourage good behavior
- Comparative advantage - specialize in what you're best at vs. your spouse
- Economies of scale - the marginal cost and effort of extra children is lower
More controversially, Levitt argues parents often overestimate their own impact relative to chance and genetics. He cites twin and adoption studies suggesting parenting style has limited impact on long-term outcomes. Levitt speculates many parents would be happier and equally effective if they stressed less over parenting choices.
Section: 1, Chapter: 3
When evaluating proposed climate solutions, be skeptical of approaches that:
- Rely primarily on market mechanisms like carbon trading rather than firm limits on pollution
- Fail to hold fossil fuel companies legally and financially accountable for their emissions
- Assume we can continue burning fossil fuels indefinitely as long as they're offset elsewhere
- Disproportionately impact poor and vulnerable communities while benefiting corporations
The climate crisis requires transparent, accessible solutions that put people and the planet ahead of profit and empower communities to take control of their energy and economic futures. Reject anything less.
Section: 2, Chapter: 7
The dominant ideological trend of the last several decades - the global triumph of free market fundamentalism (often called neoliberalism) - occurred at the very worst time from a climate perspective. Just when governments needed to intervene decisively to restructure economies away from fossil fuels, they were instead ceding more and more power to the market.
Key pillars of the free market revolution like privatization, deregulation, and corporate free trade deals acted at cross-purposes with the need for government planning to tackle emissions. Fossil fuel companies gained the freedom to pursue ever-riskier sources of carbon such as fracking. Instead of public ownership and planning for a clean energy transition, the energy sector was privatized and deregulated.
Section: 1, Chapter: 2
"Policies that simply try to harness the power of the market—by minimally taxing or capping carbon and then getting out of the way—won't be enough. If we are to rise to a challenge that involves altering the very foundation of our economy, we will need every policy tool in the democratic arsenal."
Section: 1, Chapter: 4
The introduction provides a preview of some of the controversial topics the book will explore, including:
- How sumo wrestlers sometimes throw matches for financial gain
- How some teachers cheat on standardized tests to improve their school's ranking
- How a street crack gang operates similarly to a McDonald's franchise
- How the infamous Ku Klux Klan operates similarly to a group of real estate agents
The common thread is that incentives drive behavior, sometimes in unexpected ways. The tools of economics can shine a light on hidden truths when applied correctly.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
The introduction lays out the central theme of Freakonomics - that economic analysis, when applied correctly, can reveal surprising truths about how the world really works by studying incentives. Incentives are at the core of modern life and understanding them allows us to view the world through a new lens. The authors argue conventional wisdom is often wrong and that it takes a novel way of looking at things to uncover the real truth.
Section: 1, Chapter: 1
Given the poor track record of economic forecasting to date, what would a more effective approach look like? A few key principles emerge:
- Embrace uncertainty. Rather than point forecasts, strive to quantify and communicate the full range of possible outcomes. Use probabilistic language and be explicit about your confidence level in different predictions.
- Use diverse models. Don't put all your faith in one model or method. Compare results from multiple independent approaches and be suspicious when they diverge. Use "ensemble methods" that synthesize insights from many models.
- Think in scenarios. Instead of focusing on a single "base case", map out multiple alternative futures. What has to happen for optimistic and pessimistic scenarios to play out? Which scenarios are most sensitive to your assumptions?
- Continuously update. As new data arrives, be ready to change your mind and revise your predictions. Don't get wedded to past positions. Follow the evidence where it leads, even if it's uncomfortable.
- Reward accuracy. Create incentives and accountability for forecasting precision. Keep scorecards of your prediction track record. Seek out accuracy-focused signals like prediction markets rather than just the consensus view.
Section: 1, Chapter: 3
One framework for thinking about the challenges in economic forecasting is the "signal and noise" concept. The "signal" is the true information content of economic data - the underlying trends and causal relationships we're trying to tease out. The "noise" is the random fluctuations, measurement errors, and irrelevant factors that obscure the signal.
In economic data, the noise often drowns out the signal. A few examples:
- GDP growth figures are routinely revised by multiple percentage points as new data comes in. The initial estimates are so noisy as to be nearly useless for real-time forecasting.
- Apparent patterns in things like yield curves, stock prices, or commodity prices often turn out to be random noise rather than genuine predictive signals. Statistical flukes get mistaken for meaningful economic omens.
- Economic models are built on past data that is assumed to be a fair representation of the future. But the economy's structure is constantly shifting in subtle ways. Yesterday's signal can become today's noise.
Section: 1, Chapter: 6
Economic forecasts also suffer from bias and misaligned incentives. Even when forecasters have access to the same data, their predictions are often skewed by unconscious biases and career pressures.
One common bias is overconfidence. Forecasters (and their clients) often put too much faith in complex econometric models, ignoring the uncertainties in their assumptions and the economy's inherent unpredictability. Many forecasts are presented as precise point estimates rather than ranges, creating a false sense of certainty.
Incentives also play a role. In a famous experiment, Harvard undergrads were divided into "buyers" and "sellers" of a hypothetical asset. The catch was that sellers were given a token reward if the asset price stayed high. This small incentive was enough to make sellers significantly more bullish in their price predictions vs buyers. The same dynamic plays out in the real economy - analysts affiliated with financial firms tend to make rosier GDP forecasts than independent academics.
Section: 1, Chapter: 6
One of the clearest lessons from economic history is to be deeply skeptical of overconfident economic forecasts, especially those that proclaim a "new era" of uninterrupted growth or that project present trends indefinitely into the future. Economists have a dismal record of predicting recessions and major turning points in the business cycle.
In the 2007-2008 financial crisis, for example, the median forecast from leading economists was that the economy would avoid recession and continue to grow. Even once the recession had already begun in December 2007, most economists still thought a recession was unlikely.
Part of the problem is incentives - bearish forecasts are often punished by markets and by clients who don't want to believe the party will ever end. There are also psychological biases at play, like recency bias (putting too much weight on recent events and performance) and overconfidence. Any projection that doesn't grapple with uncertainty and discuss the many ways the forecaster could be wrong is not worth very much.
Section: 1, Chapter: 2
Jan Hatzius, chief economist at Goldman Sachs, encapsulates the immense difficulties inherent to economic forecasting. He cites three main challenges:
- The economy is a dynamic, constantly evolving system with complex interrelationships and feedback loops that make it very difficult to determine cause and effect from economic data alone.
- The quality of economic data is often poor, with key indicators frequently revised months or years after they are first reported. GDP growth estimates, for example, have historically been revised by an average of 1.7 percentage points.
- Because the structure of the economy is always changing, past explanations for economic behavior may not hold in the future. Economists still debate whether the Great Recession marked a fundamental "regime change" in the economy.
As a result of these challenges, even the most sophisticated economic forecasting models have poor predictive records, routinely missing major turning points in the business cycle and failing to anticipate recessions.
Section: 1, Chapter: 2
Books about Economics
Economics
Society
History
Heuristics
Factulness Book Summary
Hans Rosling
Factfulness by Hans Rosling reveals the ten instincts that distort our perspective on the world, and provides a fact-based framework for understanding global progress and thinking more clearly about the future.
Finance
Economics
Money
Biography
The Big Short Book Summary
Michael Lewis
In "The Big Short," Michael Lewis tells the story of the contrarian investors who predicted the subprime mortgage crisis and made a fortune betting against the bubble, exposing the greed, delusion, and perverse incentives that nearly brought down the global financial system.
History
Economics
Politics
Globalization
Finance
Principles For Dealing With the Changing World Order Book Summary
Ray Dalio
Ray Dalio draws on historical patterns to provide a thought-provoking framework for understanding the cycles of rise and decline of nations, currencies, and markets, offering invaluable insights for investors and leaders navigating the complex dynamics shaping our future.
Misbehaving Book Summary
Richard Thaler
Richard Thaler chronicles the emergence of behavioral economics, challenging traditional economic assumptions about economics, and revolutionizing our understanding of decision-making. Thaler demonstrates the power of behavioral insights to improve people's lives while shedding light on the profoundly human factors that shape our choices.
Psychology
Sociology
Economics
Incentives
Super Freakonomics Book Summary
Steven D. Levitt , Stephen J. Dubner
In Superfreakonomics, Levitt and Dubner challenge conventional wisdom on topics ranging from prostitution to terrorism to global warming, using data and economic principles to uncover surprising insights and challenge readers to think like a Freak.
Psychology
Economics
Statistics
Heuristics
The Drunkard's Walk Book Summary
Leonard Mlodinow
"The Drunkard's Walk" reveals how randomness and chance play a far greater role in our lives than we typically realize, challenging our perceptions of success, decision-making, and the patterns we think we see in the world around us.
Futurism
Artificial Intelligence
Technology
Computer Science
Power And Prediction Book Summary
Ajay Agrawal, Joshua Gans, Avi Goldfarb
"Power and Prediction" argues that the true potential of AI lies not in automating individual tasks, but in enabling the redesign of entire systems and decision-making processes, which will lead to significant shifts in economic and political power as AI evolves from a tool for prediction into a catalyst for transformation.
History
Society
Economics
Guns, Germs and Steel Book Summary
Jared Diamond
In Guns, Germs, and Steel, Jared Diamond argues that the fates of human societies across history have been shaped not by innate differences between peoples, but by environmental differences in the wild plant and animal species available for domestication on each continent.
Sustainability
Climate Change
Economics
Politics
This Changes Everything Book Summary
Naomi Klein
In "This Changes Everything," Naomi Klein argues that the climate crisis challenges us to abandon the core "free market" ideology of our time, restructure the global economy, and remake our political systems - and that in the process, we have the chance to create a safer and more just world.
Psychology
Sociology
Economics
Freakonomics Book Summary
Steven D. Levitt, Stephen J. Dubner
Freakonomics is a rogue economist's exploration of the hidden side of everything, from cheating teachers and bizarre baby names to self-dealing realtors and crack-selling mama's boys, teaching you to question the world with data, dig deeper than conventional wisdom, and discern how people get what they want.
The Black Swan Book Summary
Nassim Nicholas Taleb
The Black Swan is about the extreme impact of rare and unpredictable outlier events, and how we tend to find simplistic explanations for them after the fact, making us blind to randomness and vulnerable to future Black Swans.
Prediction
Decision Making
Economics
The Signal and the Noise Book Summary
Nate Silver
In The Signal and the Noise, Nate Silver explores the art and science of prediction, explaining what separates good forecasters from bad ones and how we can all improve our understanding of an uncertain world.
Economics
Decision Making
Prediction
Game Theory
On The Edge Book Summary
Nate Silver
"On the Edge" takes readers on a captivating journey through the high-stakes world of poker, sports betting, and risk-taking, revealing the counterintuitive strategies and mental habits that allow gamblers and daredevils to thrive in the face of daunting odds.